[Viewpoint] There is no free lunch for the U.S.

Home > Opinion > Columns

print dictionary print

[Viewpoint] There is no free lunch for the U.S.

For decades, the world has complained that the dollar’s role as global reserve currency has given the United States, in a term coined by the French finance minister Valery Giscard d’Estaing, an “exorbitant privilege.”

As long as exchange rates were fixed under the Bretton Woods system, the nature of that privilege was clear: the U.S. was the only country that could freely determine its own monetary policy. All others had to adapt to the policy dictated by the U.S.

This changed with the advent of floating exchange rates in the early 1970s, which allowed more stability-conscious countries, such as Germany, to decouple from a U.S. monetary policy that they considered too inflationary.

But, even under floating exchange rates, the U.S. retained an advantage: given that the dollar remained the key global reserve currency, the U.S. could finance large external deficits at very favorable rates.

Today, the U.S. Treasury can still borrow unlimited amounts at rock-bottom interest rates. Indeed, the interest rate on inflation-protected bonds has now become -0.5 percent, even for a five-year maturity. The U.S. government is thus essentially being paid in real terms to take investors’ money - a generous offer that it is accepting on a huge scale, in the hope that channeling these resources to American consumers will boost household spending and thus generate more jobs.

The U.S. seems to have come as close as one can imagine to getting the proverbial “free lunch” - except that, as economists are fond of pointing out, there is no such thing. And that is true here as well: performing the role of reserve currency enables the U.S. to borrow on the cheap, but at the cost of any significant influence over the exchange rate, which is determined by the rest of the world’s demand for dollar assets.

Germany discovered this during the 1960s and 1970s, and resisted the Deutsche Mark’s trend toward becoming an international reserve currency. The German authorities feared that the country’s export-oriented economy would suffer from the wide exchange-rate swings that are the norm for global reserve currencies. Given the weakness of other European currencies and Germany’s desire to keep markets open, there was very little that its officials could do.

As the DM became a major international reserve currency during the 1980s and 1990s, large gyrations in the dollar exchange rate did have at times a dramatic impact on the German economy. One reason why Germany agreed to merge the DM into the euro was the hope that a monetary union would distribute the burden of the reserve-currency role over a wider area.

The U.S. economy is still rather closed (imports and exports account on average for only about 15 percent of GDP), and historically exports have never been the main engine of its growth. This is why the traditional U.S. stance has been: “It is our exchange rate, but your problem.”

So why is the U.S. now singing a different tune? The answer is obvious: America’s high unemployment rate is at 9-10 percent. This is the price that the U.S. must pay for its lunch: Americans can continue to consume a lot, but the jobs are elsewhere.

Today, China has replaced Germany (and Japan) as the world’s top exporter - but with one difference: it manages its exchange rate tightly, using capital controls and massive intervention in currency markets. As the only major economy with capital controls, China has created its own “exorbitant privilege”: it can determine its exchange rate because no other big countries impose capital controls.

The two global economic superpowers resent each other’s “exorbitant privilege.” The U.S. would like to have the Chinese jobs, and the Chinese would like to have better investment opportunities. Neither side is budging, although either could easily break the impasse.

The Chinese could abolish capital controls and let the renminbi’s exchange rate float. But the U.S. could easily end China’s privilege by restricting sales of Treasury (and other U.S.) debt to the Chinese monetary authorities. In doing so, the U.S. would break no international commitments and would not start a trade war.

Such a move is likely to be effective, given the sheer size of Chinese interventions (hundreds of billions of U.S. dollars annually), which could not easily be recycled through offshore banks without exposing the China’s central bank to many other risks.

Prohibiting the Chinese authorities from buying U.S. debt would be tantamount to imposing capital controls, thereby breaking China’s monopoly on such instruments. But it might also mean an end to America’s position at the center of the world’s financial system - and thus an end to its own “exorbitant privilege.”

There really is no free lunch. The U.S. must choose between job creation, which requires a more competitive exchange rate, and cheap financing of its external and fiscal deficits.

While China and the U.S. battle it out, each trying to retain its own “exorbitant privilege,” Europe seems to be stuck in the middle, suffering from the same disadvantages of the U.S. position, but enjoying none of its privileges.

The euro is also a global reserve currency, but most eurozone governments’ financing costs are much higher than what the U.S. Treasury pays. This is one of the costs of the incomplete nature of financial integration in Europe.

*The writer is director of the Centre for European Policy Studies.


By Daniel Gros
Log in to Twitter or Facebook account to connect
with the Korea JoongAng Daily
help-image Social comment?
s
lock icon

To write comments, please log in to one of the accounts.

Standards Board Policy (0/250자)