[Viewpoint] A tale of two defaults

Home > Opinion > Columns

print dictionary print

[Viewpoint] A tale of two defaults

Once upon a time, there was a country plagued by large deficits, high inflation and decades of economic stagnation. When economic problems once again became acute, the country’s leadership embraced a radical approach to achieving price stability.

A new currency was introduced and pegged to the U.S. dollar at a one-to-one exchange rate. A new law stipulated that this quasi-monetary union was to last forever. Moreover, the economy was opened, state enterprises were privatized and the country participated in an important regional free-trade initiative.

Initially, the new arrangement worked very well. Growth returned, and confidence among foreign investors was such that large inflows of foreign direct investment, especially in the banking sector, arrived.

But, after about 10 years, the success story turned bitter. The region’s dominant trading partner devalued, and the U.S. dollar appreciated considerably. The country thus had problems exporting. It developed external deficits and growth slowed.

Moreover, fiscal policy had not been kept under control, resulting in increasing public debt. International investors were initially quite willing to finance the government, but risk premia started to increase when the deficits became chronic.

The difficulties intensified when risk aversion in international financial markets increased markedly, owing to other emerging-market defaults. When the risk premia threatened to become unbearable, the international community responded with large financial support packages, financed principally by the International Monetary Fund and friendly countries.

The first rescue package envisaged a resumption of growth, a decline in the fiscal deficit and structural reforms. None of this was achieved, as the economy deteriorated under the impact of the fiscal measures, which were not offset by a surge in exports, because wages could not be lowered to gain competitiveness.

One year later, risk premia were even higher than before, and a second bailout package was put together, followed by a large “voluntary” debt rescheduling.

But none of this was enough to restore the confidence of international investors, who were not convinced that the government could service its debt in the face of mounting social resistance and an economy that continued to contract. Even worse, the country’s savers lost trust in their own government, and started to withdraw their deposits. As the deposit flight accelerated, the economy went into a tailspin and social tensions exploded. The government fell, and one of its fleeting successors announced a cessation of payments to foreign bondholders and an end to the currency peg.

The country was Argentina, which took about 10 years to move from its hard exchange-rate peg to the dollar, introduced in 1991, to its messy default at the turn of 2001-2.

The Greek experience - so far, at least - looks like a replay of the Argentine drama. Greece also had a history of fiscal problems and inflation, which were supposed to be cured by admission to the EU’s Economic and Monetary Union in 2001 (coincidentally, just as Argentina was preparing to default). Its first decade in EMU was also characterized by rapid economic growth, fueled mainly by abundant and cheap capital inflows.

But during this first decade, a key underlying problem emerged as Greece lost competitiveness relative to Germany, just as Argentina had lost competitiveness to Brazil.

While Argentina had been hit by the fallout from the emerging-market debt crisis of the late 1990’s, Greece is now being hit by the increase in risk aversion since the financial crisis of 2008. As with Argentina a decade ago, Greece no longer looks solvent to international investors when they consider the country’s slow growth and higher risk premia. The Greek fiscal and external deficits are about three times larger, and the accumulated debt level is more than twice that of predefault Argentina.

The first large bailout package for Greece has also met a fate similar to Argentina’s. One year on, risk premia are even higher, a second package is being put together and private creditors are being asked to roll over their bond holdings “voluntarily.”

Greece is also receiving much more foreign financial support than Argentina did. With the two rescue packages, Greece has been promised official credits worth 230 billion euros ($327.6 billion)- more than 100 percent of its GDP.

On top of this, Greece has received 90 billion euros from the ECB (at an interest rate of 1.25 percent). This huge funding has so far saved the Greek banking system from collapse, and it constitutes the key advantage of joining a real monetary union as opposed Argentina’s ‘quasi-monetary union’ with the USD. But what happens if, like in Argentina, deposit flight continues and accelerates?

If Greek savers withdraw only one-half of their remaining deposits, the ECB will have to lend another 100 billion euros to Greek banks to keep them afloat. Indeed, Greece might ultimately require more than 400 billion euros in official support - almost 200 percent of its GDP today.

If Greece were to follow the Argentine script and be forced to leave the eurozone after a messy default, its nominal GDP is likely to be halved. In that case, the Greek government’s debt to its eurozone partners would be equivalent to 400 percent of its GDP, very little of which would be repaid. Argentina defaulted on its private debt, but repaid all its official debt.

Karl Marx famously wrote that history repeats itself as farce. In the case of Greece, history might turn out more like a much larger version of Argentina’s tragedy.

*Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2011.
The writer is director of the Center for European Policy Studies.


By Daniel Gros
Log in to Twitter or Facebook account to connect
with the Korea JoongAng Daily
help-image Social comment?
s
lock icon

To write comments, please log in to one of the accounts.

Standards Board Policy (0/250자)