The pope and the party

Home > Opinion > Columns

print dictionary print

The pope and the party

As the 20th century neared, Pope Leo XIII, grieving for humanity’s choice between atheistic socialism and venal liberalism, commissioned Catholic intellectuals to devise a better solution. Named Corporatism and set forth in the 1891 encyclical Rerun Novarum, Leo’s interwar successor, Pius XI, recounted that it “laid down for all mankind the surest rules to solve that difficult problem of human relations called ‘the social question.’?”

Corporatism (which should be distinguished from the tripartite bargaining structures that emerged in many countries in the 1970s under the name “neo-corporatism”) became the most influential ethically motivated intervention into economics in modern history. As Catholic social doctrine until the late 20th century, Corporatism still shapes constitutions, laws and attitudes throughout the world. It can be distilled into four tenets:

Equality is a cruel illusion: people are happiest if rightly placed in a hierarchy legitimized by Catholic teachings.

Competition is spiritually demeaning. Associations, committees of Catholic business owners, labor leaders, and official, must set quotas, prices, and wages within vertically connected swaths of the economy called corporations. A typical Corporatist economy might contain thirty or so corporations, foods, heavy industry, textiles, chemicals among others, each encompassing raw materials, production, distribution and retailing firms. International trade and new firms are undesirable, because they undermine associations’ power.

Private property is legitimatized by owners’ obedience to Church and association but delegitimized by competition.

The principle of subsidiarity devolves authority unneeded at higher levels to the lowest feasible level throughout the hierarchy. Mussolini established the first Corporatist economy, albeit substituting “Fascist” for “Catholic” throughout. State holding companies controlled key listed firms directly; and associations controlled the rest, reconciling totalitarianism with nominally private ownership.

Italy, its foreign trade suppressed, escaped the trade wars of the Great Depression. In 1931, Pius XI took credit. “Anyone who gives even slight attention to the matter will easily see .?.?. the obvious advantages in the system .?.?. The various classes work together peacefully; socialist organizations and their activities are repressed.” He exulted that Leo’s “Catholic principles on the social question have .?.?. passed little by little into the patrimony of all human society .?.?. not only in non-Catholic books and journals but also in legislative halls and courts of justice.”

Indeed, Corporatism spread to country after country. In 1932, it was embraced by clerico-fascist Austria, under Engelbert Dollfuss. Falangist Spain under Francisco Franco and Portugal under Antonio de Oliveira Salazar followed. Interwar Poland, Greece, Albania, Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania adopted forms of Corporatism. So did Hitler’s Germany, though in greatly modified form.

Vichy France embraced Corporatism, as did German protectorates over Belgium and the Czech lands, as well as Slovakia under Monsignor Jozef Tiso. By the 1960s, most Latin American countries were avowedly corporatist dictatorships. Lebanon’s Falangist Party gave voice to its Maronite Catholics.

Indeed, the prominence of Corporatism in Catholic education is remarkable. In their book Young Trudeau, Max Nemni, Monique Nemni and William Johnson quote from Canadian leader Pierre Trudeau’s 1930’s notes on Corporatism from a class at the elite Jesuit academy where he studied: “The democratic principle has contributed to the undermining of civilization by impeding the development of the elite.” Likewise, “Liberalism leads to excesses: to unemployment, anarchy. The ideal is corporatism, which does not separate people into parties, but unites their interests.”

Today, Catholic and Islamic countries, as well as former French, Spanish and Portuguese colonies, all of which tend to have Corporatist institutional residues, also correlate with depressed living standards. Corporatist institutions plausibly retard development. Sanctified hierarchies stifle initiative. It seems to have evaded Pius XI that unchecked power might be more spiritually demeaning than competition. Corporatist subsidiarity lets the top of the hierarchy determine its own powers, while banishing competition and lauding private property generates inequality and inefficiency simultaneously.

As these failings grew manifest, the Church backpedaled in the 1960s, and John Paul II finally repudiated Corporatism. Today, few Catholics even know of the doctrine.

But interwar Corporatism is resurrected. Forsaking socialism, China didn’t adopt capitalism but kept the Communist Party atop a self-legitimized hierarchy.

True, central planners no longer set wages, prices, interest rates and quotas; but party cadres, not market forces, control the economy’s commanding heights. Industry ministries oversee vertical swaths of firms. State-controlled banks allocate capital. State-owned enterprises, or their subsidiaries, dominate key markets, as in interwar Italy. A subsidiarity principle even grants senior cadres discretion in delegating powers to underlings. How odd of Mao’s heirs, however accidentally, to resurrect this forsaken Catholic ideology.

China’s rapid growth has rescued multitudes from abject poverty, and quasi-Corporatist arrangements are clearly better than Mao’s Great Leap Forward and Cultural Revolution. But that is faint praise. Corporatism elsewhere begat vast inequalities, corruption and dictatorships that eventually proved unsustainable.

The saga of Corporatism cautions economists against dismissing ethical concerns about markets. But it also warns theologians that economics contains real truths, however unattractive. Finally, it counsels Chinese technocrats against dogma-driven economic policies.


*The author is dean and professor at the National University of Singapore Business School. This column was coauthored by Randall Morck, university professor and Jarislowsky Chair in finance at the Alberta School of Business.

by Bernard Yeung
Log in to Twitter or Facebook account to connect
with the Korea JoongAng Daily
help-image Social comment?
s
lock icon

To write comments, please log in to one of the accounts.

Standards Board Policy (0/250자)